About this time very year, as the clocks go back, I ask my
students: How do I hedge risk?
Eventually we stumble on the answer which involves buying an asset whose
prices changes, or returns in financial language, are negatively correlated
with those of my current portfolio. Thus
I give up a little of the returns from my current portfolio and add an asset
whose returns will be high (low) when those of my current portfolio will be low
(high). And so I ensure, through the
purchase (giving up of some of returns) of a hedge, that my returns or income
stream is better stabilised. The hedge
will not make you rich and “will not make you look five pounds thinner” but
will be preferred by anyone who wishes to stabilise returns from their
portfolio over a larger range of possible events. The price that people are willing to pay for
hedges can give us very useful information on the market’s perception of risk.
Let us, for example, consider credit default swaps on sovereign debt. These instruments are simply instrument designed to make
a risky government bond into a risk-free government bond (you can buy them on corporates but let's concentrate on govvies). The holder of a risky bond buys a hedge from
someone who wishes to sell insurance. The
seller of the credit default swap (CDS) collects the premia from the owner of
the risky bond and insures against default by promising to pay the par value of
the bond in the event of a default, or “credit event” by the original debt
issuer. In the event of no default, the
seller of the CDS simply collects premia and the owner of the bond has reduces
his stream of payoffs by the amount of the insurance paid. The returns from the risky bonds are thus
shared between the owner and the seller of the CDS and in principle the
combination of holding a risky bond plus a CDS “insurance” contract recovers a
risk-free bond for the bond holder. The
seller of the CDS is just collecting insurance premia, having calculated that
the expected value of these premia are no less than the cost of par value of
the bonds insured times the probability of default.
The buyer of the CDS pays a percentage of their notional
principal and this is called the CDS spread and given reasonably ordered markets
are indicative of the riskiness of a given sovereign’s (or corporate's) debt. There are a number of caveats attached to
reading the spreads as indicating risk directly: (i) liquidity in CDS markets,
there are over the counter may not always be high, which means spreads may
reflect time-varying liquidity premia; (ii) insurance premia may include fixed
cost, which drives the spread up; (iii) they reflect risk aversion rather that
credit risk, per se, and, relatedly (iv) may reflect a more general contagion
rather than an individual country or sovereign risk. And so we have to be very careful in interpreting the level of spreads and their changes.
But for the sake of telling a story, let us now look at this CDS spreads for 10
year protection for a group of advanced economies in and outside the Euro
Area. The actual spreads suggest that Spain
and Italy lie outside the norm, with spreads at around 300bp. But if we simply re-index the series for
January 2010, which is rather arbitrary admittedly, but we might use a start date
of sorts for the Euro-crisis – it is the date that the EU cast doubts on theGreek deficit numbers – we can observe a bifurcation of sorts between the
change in the spread between 2010 and today for the EMU countries and non-EMU
countries. The latter have been
relatively flat, implying the financial market price have not priced in especially
higher rates of Soveriegn risk, even though sustained economic growth has not returned. But for the four Euro Area economies Italy, France, Germany
and Spain, CDS spreads seemed to have, at least, tripled.
Whether this is contagion or liquidity or a true measure of heightened Euro
Area risk, I leave for another time. But
the price of a hedge does seem to say something clear cut about the continuing
problems of the Euro Area and that much work remains to be done.